Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

download Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

of 8

Transcript of Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    1/8

    Sergio Cesaratto Gli scenari del teatrino europeo

    2010

    Il 16-17 dicembre si riunisce in Belgio il Consiglio dei leader europei. Quali sono gli scenariche lEuropa ha di fronte?

    Alla irrisolta crisi di solvibilit della Grecia si in questo autunno aggiunta quella dellIrlanda

    e a ruota il contagio, che si manifesta con un aumento dei tassi di interesse sui titoli pubblici,

    arrivato anche allItalia via Portogallo e Spagna e ora persino alla Germania. Quali sono le

    prospettive? Abbiamo di fronte tre scenari: 1) tamponare con un po di liquidit la situazione

    dei paesi periferici chiedendo loro di aggiustare i propri conti con sacrifici interni;. 2)

    anticipare la rottura e gestirla evitandone gli aspetti pi dolorosi, per quello che si pu; 3)

    attaccare i problemi alla radice nella direzione di costruire una unione politica ed economica

    funzionante.

    La crisi europea assomiglia alle molte delle crisi debitorie nei i paesi in via di sviluppo il cuiultimo clamoroso caso stato il default dellArgentina nel 2002. In pillole, la costituzione

    dellUnione monetaria europea (UME) nel 1999 ha favorito flussi di capitale a buon mercato

    dai paesi centrali dellEuropa (Germania e Francia in primis) a quelli periferici, i famosi

    PIGS. La politica monetaria della BCE stata al contempo improntata a bassi tassi nominali

    di interesse essendo ritagliata sulla Germania, per compensare le sue politiche di moderazione

    fiscale e salariale che poco sostenevano domanda e produzione. I flussi di capitale hanno

    determinato un boom edilizio e lindebitamento delle famiglie in Spagna e Irlanda, e del

    settore pubblico in Grecia. Ledilizia un volano delleconomia questi paesi sono infatti

    cresciuti assai, e cos i loro salari nominali e prezzi. Questo ha implicato che i tassi di

    interesse reali[1] diventassero, in quei paesi, assai bassi, stimolando ancor di pi la domanda.La produttivit i questi paesi cresciuta pi che in Germania, ma qui i salari nominali

    crescevano meno della produttivit, nella periferia essi aumentavano pi della produttivit,

    sicch essa perdeva competitivit. La Germania e il suo entourage (Austria, Paesi Bassi ecc)

    guadagnava cos in termini di esportazioni nette verso la periferia sia perch la domanda in

    quei paesi cresceva molto, che per la loro perdita di competitivit. Nei fatti le esportazioni di

    capitali dai paesi centrali finivano per finanziare lacquisto di prodotti dai medesimi paesi. Ma

    se questo accade per una serie di anni, i paesi periferici finiscono per cumulare un forte debito

    estero. Inizialmente questo era, in Spagna e Irlanda, solo privato, ma ad esso si aggiunto,

    una volta scoppiata la crisi, quello del settore pubblico che si indebitato a sua volta per

    soccorrere le banche nazionali indebitate con quelle dellEuropa centrale. Se i paesi creditori a

    un certo punto ritengono che i debitori non possano restituire il debito, possono smettere dirifinanziarglielo, e i debitori dichiarano la bancarotta (default).

    Una soluzione a questa situazione implica: a) nel breve periodo assicurare a questi paesi

    liquidit sufficiente e a buon mercato per non fallire; e b) nel medio periodo risolvere il loro

    problema di solvibilit stimolando il loro output ed esportazioni. Esaminiamo dunque i tre

    scenari.

    1. Nel primo scenario, gi in opera, gli aiuti europei e una timidissima BCE tamponano la

    crisi di liquidit sostenendo i titoli dei paesi debitori qualora i mercati non vogliano pi farlo o

    lo farebbero solo a tassi esorbitanti, ma lo fanno in misura insufficiente senza davvero

    incidere sui tassi usurai che tali paesi si trovano a pagare (i quali aggravano il debito). Al

    contempo la deflazione fiscale e salariale loro richiesta determina una caduta del loro PIL, conconseguente caduta delle entrate fiscali, sicch il riaggiustamento dei conti una fatica di

    Sisifo (per non parlare dei sacrifici sociali che ci comporta). Tradizionalmente aggiustamenti

  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    2/8

    dei conti interni sono stati accompagnati da una svalutazione della moneta, che rilanciando le

    esportazione ne ha compensato i danni sul PIL. Ma ora le monete nazionali non ci sono pi!

    Per giunta la stessa Germania si fa campione della deflazione, e ci aggrava la crisi della

    domanda aggregata a livello europeo e globale. I mercati tutto questo lo sanno, e per questo il

    fallimento dei paesi periferici e della moneta unica allordine del giorno. Se fanno

    fallimento i paesi debitori, faranno anche fallimento i paesi creditori (USA inclusi) e questasarebbe la madre di tutte le crisi.

    2. Una rottura ordinata dellUME, con la fuoriuscita dei paesi periferici, affare

    complicatissimo (Blejer and Levy-Yeyati 2010; Eichengreen 2010). Il fatto centrale di cui

    tener conto che il debito esterno di tali paesi continuerebbe a esser denominato in euro.

    Misurato nelle nuove valute locali, che cadrebbero di valore, e di molto, rispetto alleuro, il

    valore di quel debito aumenterebbe, per cui esso dovrebbe certamente subire quello che si

    chiama un haircut (un taglio dei capelli), cio essere rinegoziato (ci si accorda che una parte

    non viene restituita, e il resto restituito in tempi pi lunghi). Ma se i mercati subdorano questa

    eventualit, la speculazione si scatenerebbe determinando un immediato disordinato

    default. Allora la decisione di una rottura dovrebbe essere segretamente presa prima che imercati sospettino qualcosa dunque un po prima che il sistema crolli di suo -, in un

    consesso che non pu escludere, tuttavia, USA, Cina e Giappone, almeno, oltre ai principali

    paesi europei. Nei tempi di Wikileaks tenere il segreto non facile! Il vantaggio di riacquisire

    la propria moneta sarebbe nel rilancio delle esportazioni, ma misure per impedire che si

    scateni una forte inflazione interna sarebbero necessarie. Non sarebbe invece necessario

    stampare preventivamente nuove banconote, le attuali gi sono contraddistinte per paese (una

    S dopo il numero di serie individua per esempio quelle italiane). Misure drastiche di

    controllo dei capitali sarebbero ovviamente necessarie. Se fosse la Germania (e forse una

    recalcitrante Francia) a lasciare, ci costituirebbe di per s un taglio ai debiti esteri denominati

    in una moneta, leuro, che svaluterebbe rispetto al nuovo Deutsche Mark. Se poi ci che

    rimane dellUME si sfasciasse, tutti si tornerebbe alle monete nazionali e il debito esterosarebbe denominato in quelle, il che sancirebbe un haircutdi fatto.

    3. Linefficacia del primo scenario, e la drammaticit del secondo, potrebbero col tempo far

    addivenire a soluzioni pi ragionevoli. Con riguardo ai problemi di sostenibilit a breve, una

    pi incisiva azione della BCE nel sostenere i titoli di stato e la europeizzazione di parte dei

    debiti (come proposto, fra gli altri, da Tremonti) assicurerebbe i mercati consentendo un loro

    rifinanziamento a costi contenuti. I problemi strutturali dovrebbero essere poi affrontati

    invertendo la moderazione fiscale e salariale tedesca di modo che tale economia perda un po

    di competitivit e al contempo rilanci la domanda interna[2]. Daltronde solo operando con

    misure opposte a quelle che hanno caratterizzato sinora lUME se ne possono invertire le

    tendenze. Questo appare al momento inaccettabile alla Germania che fonda il proprio modello

    di crescita su disciplina interna ed esportazioni con in mente lespansione nei paesi extra-

    europei.

    Se dio veramente acceca chi vuole perdere, nel meeting del 16-7 dicembre i paesi europei

    decideranno piani draconiani di rientro dal debito pubblico a cui nostro paese arriver senza

    un governo che possa autorevolmente opporsi a tale follia.

    [1] Il tasso di interesse reale la differenza fra il tasso di interesse nominale e il tasso di inflazione. Se

    prendiamo 100 in prestito al tasso nominale del 5%, e il tasso di inflazione del 4% (per cui ci che

    restituiremo fra un anno vale il 4% di meno in termini di potere dacquisto), il tasso reale che

    effettivamente paghiamo 1%.

    [2] Un obiettivo accettabilissimo per i tedeschi sarebbe di accettare che i salari nominali crescessero in

    quel paese al tassi di crescita della produttivit pi il 2% che il tasso di inflazione obiettivo della BCE.Il

    http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5326http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5326
  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    3/8

    16-17 dicembre si riunisce in Belgio il Consiglio dei leader europei. Quali sono gli scenari che lEuropa ha

    di fronte?

    Leaving the euro: Whats in the box?

    Mario I. Blejer Eduardo Levy-Yeyati21 July 2010

    Rumours of Eurozone break-up are mounting. This column argues that exiting a strong

    currency for a weak one poses almost unthinkable challenges, from the redenomination of

    contracts and the imposition of bank restrictions to the restructuring of external debt and

    limiting of capital mobility. Lessons from Argentina illustrate just how radical the changes

    would need to be.

    The turmoil in Europe is not abating. True, some calm has returned to the markets after the

    initial storm, but tenacious misgivings about the euro project in general are growing, driven

    by disenchantment with the policy responses and a realisation of the magnitude of the

    problem.

    Something that was unthinkable six months ago is happening today. There are, still few

    indeed, but undeniable mounting calls for euro exit and not only from euro sceptics across

    the Atlantic (see Feldstein 2010, Financial Times 2010, and Baldwin 2010for a summary of

    the debate on Vox.)

    While faint exit pleads could be heard in Germany, as a way to avoid bearing the cost of the

    bailout, the louder calls are coming from the economies under pressure and looking to regain

    competitiveness, with Greece in front of a potentially larger number of countries willing or

    forced to give up the single-currency project.

    Switching from a strong to a weak currencyBut the process of launching a new, weaker, national currency to substitute a stronger one as

    legal tender is, to be sure, a very complex one. What do we know about this process?

    Eichengreen (2007) provides an analysis of this event but when it comes to hard facts the

    answer is simple. We know virtually nothing.

    Indeed, it is unclear whether those toying with this type of solution have analysed the

    preconditions and consequences of such a move since there is not much precedent for an

    episode of this kind in recent economic history.

    Abandoning a battered currency in favour of a stronger one (dollarisation in the jargon) hasbeen more frequent, and is probably easier in comparison (see for example Levy Yeyati and

    Sturzenegger 2002). Creating or reintroducing a national currency with the deliberate

    intention to weaken itrelative to the existing one (and to all other world currencies, for that

    matter) is an altogether different and much more complicated endeavour, particularly if this

    has to be done in times of distress and mistrust of domestic policies.

    Argentina 2002The closest, although certainly not identical, precedent to this course of action is Argentines

    exit from a currency board arrangement to float a weakening peso in 2002, an event that has

    important common aspects with the case in point. While still far, in many respects, from anew drachma or a new peseta, the episode nonetheless offers some interesting pointers as

    to what the whole affair involves.

    http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5325http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3573http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5034http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5034http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5325http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/3573http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5034
  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    4/8

    At the risk of generalising and omitting, the Argentine lessons can be summarised under four

    categories. If a country is willing to seriously entertain the idea of introducing a new, weaker,

    currency (which for simplicity we could call the peso), it needs to be willing to deal with:

    the peso-ification of contracts,

    the imposition of heavy restrictions to commercial bank operations,

    an external debt restructuring, and

    the use of capital and exchange controls at least temporarily.

    Crucially, all of these four types of tribulations, which come on top of the potential

    inflationary consequences that follow any normal devaluation, need to be tackled jointly and

    up front, as they are likely to be anticipated by agents and markets.

    Exit costs can only grow larger if the decision process is protracted and marred by

    improvisation and half-baked patches.

    Below we briefly discuss why these four issues are an almost inescapable consequence of

    leaving the strong currency:

    Peso-ification or redenomination of

    contractsThe new currency needs to create its own transactional demand and requires a legal

    framework that makes it the sole legal tender and unit of account. This requires the forced

    redenomination of all contracts in the economy. Regarding prices and wages as well as other

    flows of funds the redenomination may not create very serious disruptions.

    The redenomination ofaccumulatedstocks, however, particularly those arising from domestic

    financial contracts, becomes an extremely thorny issue.

    On the one hand, if the new currency succeeds in achieving a real devaluation (i.e.,

    this if the pass-through of the nominal devaluation to inflation is reasonably low), the

    forced peso-ification of financial contracts results in heavy and asymmetrical balance

    sheet effects.

    In particular, the losses experienced by domestic euro debtors would more than offset the

    gains from a more competitive economy and make the whole euro exit strategy self defeating

    (see Frankel 2005).

    On the other hand, the peso-ification of bank deposits and credits could have a

    massive redistributive impact (benefiting net bank debtors and hurting net deposit

    holders) and could bring up violent social and political reactions.

    It would also immediately trigger a bank run, as depositors run to protect their savings by

    switching them back into hard currency. Indeed a bank run may be unavoidable and precede

    the exit, as the Argentine case illustrates.

    The Argentinean bank run started in early 2001, nine months before the abandonment of the

    currency board arrangement. This is because the mere expectation of an exit is enough to fuel

    a deposit run, as well as a credit crunch, in anticipation of the inevitable peso-ification (see

    Levy Yeyati et al. 2010).

    A deposit freezeTo counter the deposit run and to avoid massive bank failures until the economy is out of thewoods, a temporary deposit freeze would be needed. Crucially, to minimise the damage, the

  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    5/8

    freeze needs to be selective, excluding sight and savings deposits needed for everyday

    transactions.

    Argentina, again, is a good example albeit negative. The gate dropping on all deposit

    withdrawals in November 2001 (the so-called corralito) was a misguided choice that caused

    a liquidity crunch that only contributed to the downward spiral in economic activity and

    market sentiment.

    This misguided policy was the immediate cause of the government collapse. By contrast, the

    deposit restructuring in January 2002, that peso-ified and froze only term deposits, slowed

    down the run thereby preserving the payments system.

    Needless to say, these options were (as they always are) desperate measures to cope with a

    terminal crisis, and suffered from many shortcomings that are inevitable when policy is made

    in a crisis. But even the most careful preparations may not prevent the financial panic

    surrounding an anticipated conversion.

    An external debt restructuringThis is the flipside of the peso-ification of domestic financial contracts. External debt underinternational law cannot be redenominated by the government but, following the peso-

    ification of state revenues and expenditures, it becomes very difficult to service on its original

    terms. Therefore international debt relief could come through a negotiated debt exchange.

    Importantly, however, such a restructuring is not restricted to the sovereign. Corporate euro

    debtors would suffer the same balance-sheet shock and, with the government unable to fund a

    bailout, would be forced to renegotiate their liabilities.

    In Argentina that was a painful and protracted but essentially successful process. Firms

    restructured their debts under the umbrella provided by the combination of sovereign default

    and capital controls that inhibited debt servicing abroad. In this way, bankruptcies wereavoided but the access to international markets by the corporate sector remained impaired for

    many years. Besides this distinction, however, the main lesson from the Argentine experience

    is that it is unrealistic to conceive a euro exit without a debt default.

    Capital and exchange-rate controlsEuros (and other reserve currencies) will be precious in the event of a euro exit. Financial

    uncertainty fuels capital flight just at the time when the country needs to fund a narrowing but

    still sizeable current-account deficit. This scarcity of euros will probably be exacerbated by a

    loss of access to international capital markets.

    As a result, traditional restrictive measures such as the obligation to surrender export proceedsto the central bank, often coupled with capital outflow and exchange-rate controls, are

    necessary. All of these measures were launched in Argentina in early 2002 and contributed to

    stabilise the transition.

    In fact, it may not be possible to enforce the redenomination of contracts nor the deposit

    freeze without capital controls; without them all settlements would immediately move abroad.

    Again, the lesson here is that conceiving a euro exit while maintaining full convertibility is

    probably wishful thinking.

    The euro difference: Harder than acurrency board arrangement

  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    6/8

    Argentinas abandonment of its hard peg has some similarities but also marked differences

    with the current situation regarding euro exit. Leaving the currency board arrangement was

    actually simpler than the introduction of a new currency in that the currency board

    arrangement never eliminated the use of the local currency for transaction purposes, the basis

    of the demand for money.

    In Argentina, the devaluation caught people with pesos in their wallets, and the need forliquidity supported a steady demand for pesos all through the first quarter of 2002 when it

    depreciated by 300% (see De la Torre et al. 2003). By contrast, a new drachma or a new

    peseta would need to create from scratch a demand for a currency born weaker by design.

    Could it work?

    Everything is possible but, as noted, there are no real precedents and, just judging from the

    costs involved in redistributing wealth through the redenomination of contracts, imposing

    bank restrictions, restructuring external debt, and limiting capital mobility, it is certainly not

    the easiest way out.

    ReferencesBaldwin, Richard (2010), A re-cap of Vox columns on the Eurozone crisis, VoxEU.org, 10

    May.

    De la Torre, Augusto, Eduardo Levy Yeyati, and Sergio Schmukler (2003), Living and Dying

    with Hard Pegs,Economia, 43-107.

    Eichengreen, Barry (2007), "Eurozone breakup would trigger the mother of all financial

    crises", VoxEU.org, 17 November.

    Feldstein, Martin (2010), Let Greece Take a Holiday from the Eurozone, Financial Times,

    17 February.

    Financial Times, Dis-membering the euro, 14 July, Lex.

    Frankel, Jeffrey (2005), Contractionary Currency Crashes in Developing Countries, IMF

    Staff Papers, 52(2).

    Levy Yeyati, Eduardo, Maria Soledad Martinez Peria, and Sergio Schmukler (2010), Market

    Discipline under Macroeconomic Risk,Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking.

    Levy Yeyati, Eduardo, and Federico Sturzenegger (2002) (eds.), Dollarization: Debates and

    Policy Alternatives, MIT Press.

    This article may be reproduced with appropriate attribution. See Copyright (below).

    The euro: love it or leave it?Barry Eichengreen

    4 May 2010

    Originally posted 17 November 2007, this Vox column is more relevant than ever arguing that

    adopting the euro is effectively irreversible. Leaving would require lengthy preparations,

    which, given the anticipated devaluation, would trigger the mother of all financial crises.

    National households and firms would shift deposits to other Eurozone banks producing a

    http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5034http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729http://www.ft.com/cms/s/3/876a9fe6-8f67-11df-ac5d-00144feab49a.htmlhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB8QFjAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.imf.org%2FExternal%2FPubs%2FFT%2Fstaffp%2F2004%2F00-00%2Ffranke.pdf&ei=mNFFTPHuBc-TsQa8iJjIAQ&usg=AFQjCNGM4FA8z1BUORFXgtgLgdk4Ayb4NAhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CCcQFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fmitpress.mit.edu%2Fcatalog%2Fitem%2Fdefault.asp%3Ftid%3D9197%26ttype%3D2&rct=j&q=Dollarization%3A%20Debates%20and%20Policy%20Alternatives%20MIT&ei=v9FFTN2eEJWgsQaployoAQ&usg=AFQhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CCcQFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fmitpress.mit.edu%2Fcatalog%2Fitem%2Fdefault.asp%3Ftid%3D9197%26ttype%3D2&rct=j&q=Dollarization%3A%20Debates%20and%20Policy%20Alternatives%20MIT&ei=v9FFTN2eEJWgsQaployoAQ&usg=AFQhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CCcQFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fmitpress.mit.edu%2Fcatalog%2Fitem%2Fdefault.asp%3Ftid%3D9197%26ttype%3D2&rct=j&q=Dollarization%3A%20Debates%20and%20Policy%20Alternatives%20MIT&ei=v9FFTN2eEJWgsQaployoAQ&usg=AFQhttp://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/101http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5034http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729http://www.ft.com/cms/s/3/876a9fe6-8f67-11df-ac5d-00144feab49a.htmlhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=1&ved=0CB8QFjAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.imf.org%2FExternal%2FPubs%2FFT%2Fstaffp%2F2004%2F00-00%2Ffranke.pdf&ei=mNFFTPHuBc-TsQa8iJjIAQ&usg=AFQjCNGM4FA8z1BUORFXgtgLgdk4Ayb4NAhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CCcQFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fmitpress.mit.edu%2Fcatalog%2Fitem%2Fdefault.asp%3Ftid%3D9197%26ttype%3D2&rct=j&q=Dollarization%3A%20Debates%20and%20Policy%20Alternatives%20MIT&ei=v9FFTN2eEJWgsQaployoAQ&usg=AFQhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&source=web&cd=3&ved=0CCcQFjAC&url=http%3A%2F%2Fmitpress.mit.edu%2Fcatalog%2Fitem%2Fdefault.asp%3Ftid%3D9197%26ttype%3D2&rct=j&q=Dollarization%3A%20Debates%20and%20Policy%20Alternatives%20MIT&ei=v9FFTN2eEJWgsQaployoAQ&usg=AFQhttp://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/101
  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    7/8

    system-wide bank run. Investors, trying to escape, would create a bond-market crisis. Here is

    what the train wreck would look like.

    The world economy is continually changing, but one constant is dissatisfaction with the euro.

    Toward the beginning of the decade, the main complaint was that the euro was too weak forbooming economies like Ireland. Now the complaint is that it is too strong for growth-

    challenged countries like Italy.

    To be sure, the source of the current problem is external. It stems from the fall of the dollar,

    reflecting a combination of economic and financial problems in the United States, and the

    insistence of the Chinese authorities that the renminbi should follow the greenback. But that

    does nothing to defuse the complaints.

    The negative impact is being felt by all euro-area members. But some countries where growth

    was already stagnant, such as Italy, are least able to cope. Already in June 2005, following

    two years of euro appreciation, then-Italian welfare minister Roberto Maroni declared that

    the euro has to go. Then-prime minister Silvio Berlusconi followed by calling the euro adisaster. But this earlier episode of appreciation pales in comparison with what has happened

    since. And if the dollar depreciates further and the US falls into a full-blown recession both

    of which are more likely than not calls like these will be back.

    So is the euro doomed? After seeing the number of euro-area countries rise from 10 in 1999 to

    15 at the beginning of 2008, will the process shift into reverse? If one country leaves the euro

    area by reintroducing its national currency, will others follow? Will the entire enterprise

    collapse?

    The answer is no. The decision to join the euro area is effectively irreversible.1 However

    attractive the rhetoric of defection is for populist politicians, exit is effectively impossible

    although not for the reasons suggested in earlier discussions.A first reason why members will not exit, it is argued, is the economic costs. A country that

    leaves the euro area because of problems of competitiveness would be expected to devalue its

    newly-reintroduced national currency. But workers would know this, and the resulting wage

    inflation would neutralise any benefits in terms of external competitiveness. Moreover, the

    country would be forced to pay higher interest rates on its public debt. Those old enough to

    recall the high costs of servicing the Italian debt in the 1980s will appreciate that this can be a

    serious problem.

    But for each such argument about economic costs, there is a counterargument. If

    reintroduction of the national currency is accompanied by labour market reform, real wages

    will adjust. If exit from the euro area is accompanied by the reform of fiscal institutions so

    that investors can look forward to smaller future deficits, there is no reason for interest rates to

    go up. Empirical studies show that joining the euro-area does result in a modest reduction in

    debt service costs; by implication, leaving would raise them. But this increase could be offset

    by a modest institutional reform, say, by increasing the finance ministers fiscal powers from

    Portuguese to Austrian levels. Even populist politicians know that abandoning the euro will

    not solve all problems. They will want to combine it with structural reforms.

    A second reason why members will not exit, it is argued, is the political costs. A country that

    reneges on its euro commitments will antagonise its partners. It will not be welcomed at the

    table where other European Union-related decisions were made. It will be treated as a second

    class member of the EU to the extent that it remains a member at all.

    Political costs there would be, but there would also be benefits for politicians who could claim

    that they were putting the interests of their domestic constituents first. And politics have not

    http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729#fn12http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/729#fn12
  • 7/28/2019 Sergio Cesaratto Gli Scenari Del Teatrino Europeo 2010

    8/8

    rendered countries like Denmark and Sweden that have steadfastly refused to adopt the euro

    second-class EU member states.

    The insurmountable obstacle to exit is neither economic nor political, then, but procedural.

    Reintroducing the national currency would require essentially all contracts including those

    governing wages, bank deposits, bonds, mortgages, taxes, and most everything else to be

    redenominated in the domestic currency. The legislature could pass a law requiring banks,firms, households and governments to redenominate their contracts in this manner. But in a

    democracy this decision would have to be preceded by very extensive discussion.

    And for it to be executed smoothly, it would have to be accompanied by detailed planning.

    Computers will have to be reprogrammed. Vending machines will have to be modified.

    Payment machines will have to be serviced to prevent motorists from being trapped in

    subterranean parking garages. Notes and coins will have to be positioned around the country.

    One need only recall the extensive planning that preceded the introduction of the physical

    euro.

    Back then, however, there was little reason to expect changes in exchange rates during the

    run-up and hence little incentive for currency speculation. In 1998, the founding members ofthe euro-area agreed to lock their exchange rates at the then-prevailing levels. This effectively

    ruled out depressing national currencies in order to steal a competitive advantage in the

    interval prior to the move to full monetary union in 1999. In contrast, if a participating

    member state now decided to leave the euro area, no such precommitment would be possible.

    The very motivation for leaving would be to change the parity. And pressure from other

    member states would be ineffective by definition.

    Market participants would be aware of this fact. Households and firms anticipating that

    domestic deposits would be redenominated into the lira, which would then lose value against

    the euro, would shift their deposits to other euro-area banks. A system-wide bank run would

    follow. Investors anticipating that their claims on the Italian government would beredenominated into lira would shift into claims on other euro-area governments, leading to a

    bond-market crisis. If the precipitating factor was parliamentary debate over abandoning the

    lira, it would be unlikely that the ECB would provide extensive lender-of-last-resort support.

    And if the government was already in a weak fiscal position, it would not be able to borrow to

    bail out the banks and buy back its debt. This would be the mother of all financial crises.

    What government invested in its own survival would contemplate this option? The

    implication is that as soon as discussions of leaving the euro area become serious, it is those

    discussions, and not the area itself, that will end.

    Footnote1 For details, see The Breakup of the Euro Area. Barry Eichengreen. NBER Working Paper

    No. 13393.

    http://www.nber.org/papers/w13393http://www.nber.org/papers/w13393